Reassessment of the Todaro paradox: an extended panel data analysis on developing countries
Автор: Yilmaz Ekrem, Sensoy Fatma
Журнал: Economic and Social Changes: Facts, Trends, Forecast @volnc-esc-en
Рубрика: Global experience
Статья в выпуске: 2 т.16, 2023 года.
Бесплатный доступ
This paper empirically analyzes the Todaro Paradox for eight developing countries for the period from 1992 to 2019. Having different data characteristics, we apply three different panel approaches (Fixed Effect, Random Effect, and Full Modified Ordinary Least Square) by using distinct models. Our findings from different models depict that the Todaro Paradox is valid for the sample economies. Specifically, we observe a negative relationship between the price level ratio of purchasing power parity conversion factor (GDP) to market exchange rate and urban population contrary to the price level ratio of the purchasing power parity conversion factor (GDP) to the market exchange rate - rural population nexus. Thanks to obtaining these links, we apply the third empirical model to verify the Todaro Paradox. The analysis of the price level ratio of the purchasing power parity conversion factor (GDP) to the market exchange rate and total unemployment in the urban population provides strong evidence for the validity of this paradox. Deviated from the previous literature, this paper applies the price level ratio of the purchasing power parity conversion factor (GDP) to the market exchange rate since the higher the purchasing power parity of a country, the lower the rate of rural-urban migration is expected. By using one extra variable (unemployment), we test the Todaro Paradox. This combination of variables as well as different panel techniques (Fixed Effect, Random Effect, and Full Modified Ordinary Least Square) allow us to draw more robust conclusions. To address the challenges posed by rural-urban migration, policies should be designed to promote sustainable development in both urban and rural areas. This can include measures to create employment opportunities and improve the quality of life in both areas, as well as policies to regulate migration and manage the pressures caused by rapid urbanization.
Migration, purchasing power parity, todaro paradox, urban economy, unemployment, rural economy
Короткий адрес: https://sciup.org/147240787
IDR: 147240787 | DOI: 10.15838/esc.2023.2.86.11
Текст научной статьи Reassessment of the Todaro paradox: an extended panel data analysis on developing countries
The concept of migration encompasses different perspectives. Internal migration refers to mobility within the borders of a nation (Puhani, 2001), whereas external migration refers to mobility between settlements in two or more countries (Bell et al., 2002). An individual who migrates from one country to another for employment purposes is considered an immigrant (Gimeno-Feliu et al., 2019; Jean, Jimenez, 2011; Kemnitz, 2003; Wong, 1991). Ravenstein studied the behavior patterns of individuals in relation to migration and noted that the movements of immigrants tend to be short-distance and directed towards large commercial and industrial centers (Ravenstein, 1889). As a result, migration from areas close to big cities is on the rise and has become a popular destination for immigrants seeking employment. On the other hand, residents of urban areas tend to migrate less frequently compared to their rural counterparts, leading to a higher rate of rural-tourban migration (Ravenstein, 1889). Migration that involves leaving one’s country for a different region for employment purposes can result in differences between the sending and receiving regions in terms of their economic and social characteristics (Castles, 2000) . The issue of employment is crucial in this context. Many studies have shown that unemployment is a major motivator for migration
(Herzog, Schlottmann, 1984; Kingma, 2007; Potts, Mutambirwa, 1990; Zhang, Song, 2003). Employment, as an economic concept, refers to the use of production factors for the purpose of generating income. In addressing the problem of unemployment, countries implement various policies and strategies.
Policies aimed at enhancing employment in cities can lead to migration from rural to urban areas, particularly in developing countries. Todaro and Harris modeled the factors that drive rural-tourban migration in developing nations (Todaro, 1969; Harris, Todaro, 1970). In their model, the determining factors are wage differences between rural and urban areas and employment opportunities in cities. As long as expected urban wages, adjusted by the probability of finding a job, are higher than rural wages, migration from rural to urban areas will persist. In developing countries, it takes place in two stages. Initially, migrants are unable to secure formal sector employment due to a lack of qualifications, but they find work in the informal sector. In the second stage, they switch to formal sector employment. As a result, unemployment is both a cause and a consequence of migration and will persist as long as there are wage and employment disparities between rural and urban regions (Harris, Todaro, 1970; Todaro, 1969). The duration of time required to secure formal sector employment and the availability of employment opportunities are important factors in triggering migration (Todaro, 1969). Todaro introduced the concept of the “Todaro Paradox”, which suggests that the positive effect of increasing employment opportunities in urban areas on unemployment is offset by the negative effect of rural-to-urban migration. Investments aimed at reducing urban unemployment may lead to higher unemployment, emphasizing the importance of rural development in addressing the issue (Todaro, 1976).
On the other hand, considering Purchasing Power Parity (PPP), which represents a rate of change that equalizes the purchasing power of different currencies by removing price level disparities between countries is crucial for the analysis of the Todaro paradox1. The study of PPP began several decades ago, with the most well-known method of calculation being the Geary-Khamis dollar. This method, introduced by Roy C. Geary in 1958 and developed by Salem H. Khamis in the early 1970s (Brunt, Fidalgo, 2018), combines PPP and international average prices of goods. The calculation of PPP in the USA is based on the years 1990 or 2000, and international comparisons of per capita income in Geary-Khamis dollars provide a more meaningful comparison of standard of living than per capita income at current prices (Nordhaus, 2007). The US dollar serves as the common currency in these calculations (Dornbusch, 1985).
The Todaro Paradox and purchasing power parity are two related economic concepts. The Todaro Paradox is caused by the fact that, despite high levels of urban unemployment, people still migrate from rural to urban areas in search of work. This contradicts the classical theory of migration, which states that people should only move if there are more job opportunities in the destination location (Haas et al., 2019). PPP, on the other hand, is a theory that states that the exchange rate between two currencies is equal to the ratio of the prices of a basket of goods in each country (Samuelson, 1964). In other words, PPP states that the same goods should cost the same amount in different countries after adjusting for exchange rates. The relationship between the Todaro Paradox and PPP lies in the fact that PPP is often used to measure the purchasing power of different currencies in different countries. When PPP is applied to the Todaro Paradox, it becomes clear that people are moving to urban areas not just because of the availability of jobs, but also because they believe that their purchasing power will be higher in the city, even if they are unemployed. PPP helps to shed light on the motivations behind migration in the context of the Todaro Paradox, and can help economists better understand the forces driving rural-urban migration.
In this study, the “Price level ratio of PPP conversion factor (GDP) to market exchange rate” is employed as a variable to test the correlation and causality between this factor and the rate of rural-urban migration. This relationship has not been previously examined in the existing literature on the subject. The study aims to contribute to the field by incorporating a unique variable and conducting econometric analysis using three different techniques: Fixed Effect (FE), Random Effect (RE) and Full Modified Ordinary Least Square (FMOLS).
Several propositions motivated us to conduct this investigation.
First, we aim to address the socio-economic problems associated with migration, which are crucial for development, within the context of the Todaro Paradox. The purpose of the paper is to emphasize the importance of this critical topic and to consider comprehensively its implications, which have been overlooked by the empirical literature.
Second, the Todaro Paradox explains why people in developing countries migrate from rural areas to urban areas despite worsening economic conditions in the latter. Focusing on the Todaro Paradox by using the correct variables can provide insights into the motivations behind rural-urban migration and the push and pull factors that influence this phenomenon.
Third, policymakers can better target interventions aimed at reducing rural-urban migration and promoting sustainable development in developing countries by understanding the Todaro Paradox.
Fourth, rural-urban migration can have both positive and negative effects on the development of a country. By studying the Todaro Paradox, researchers can better understand the results of rural-to-urban migration and identify ways to mitigate its negative effects while enhancing its positive effects.
Our contributions to the literature can be divided into two folds. First, we use the price level ratio of the PPP conversion factor (GDP) to the market exchange rate since the higher the PPP of a country, the lower the rate of rural-urban migration is expected. By using one extra variable (unemployment), we test the Todaro Paradox. This combination of variables allows us to draw more meaningful conclusions and have the potential to reveal new insights into economic literature.
Second, the FE, RE and FMOLS methods allow for a more comprehensive and nuanced examination of the relationship between the price level ratio of PPP conversion factor and other variables related to rural-urban migration, leading to more robust results and a better understanding of the underlying causal relationships. Moreover, these techniques allow for the control of potential omitted variable bias, cross-sectional dependence, and endogeneity.
Список литературы Reassessment of the Todaro paradox: an extended panel data analysis on developing countries
- Arellano J.P. (1981). Do more jobs in the modern sector increase urban unemployment? Journal of Development Economics, 8(2). DOI: 10.1016/0304-3878(81)90031-6
- Bell M., Blake, M., Boyle P. et al. (2002). Cross-national comparison of internal migration: Issues and measures. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series A: Statistics in Society. DOI: 10.1111/1467-985X.00247
- Blomqvist A.G. (1978). Urban job creation and unemployment in LDCs. Todaro vs. Harris and Todaro. Journal of Development Economics, 5(1). DOI: 10.1016/0304-3878(78)90039-1
- Breusch T.S., Pagan A.R. (1980). The Lagrange multiplier test and its applications to model specification in econometrics. The Review of Economic Studies, 47(1), 239. DOI: 10.2307/2297111
- Brueckner J.K., Kim H.A. (2001). Land markets in the Harris-Todaro model: A new factor equilibrating rural-urban migration. Journal of Regional Science, 41(3). DOI: 10.1111/0022-4146.00228
- Brueckner J.K., Thisse J.F., Zenou Y. (1999), Why is central Paris rich and downtown Detroit poor? An amenity-based theory. European Economic Review, 43(1). DOI: 10.1016/S0014-2921(98)00019-1
- Brunt L., Fidalgo A. (2018). Why 1990 international Geary-Khamis dollars cannot be a foundation for reliable long run comparisons of GDP. SSRN Electronic Journal. DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3292792
- Castles S. (2000). International migration at the beginning of the twenty-first century: Global trends and issues. International Social Science Journal, 52(165), 269–281. DOI: 10.1111/1468-2451.00258
- Chaudhuri S. (2007). Foreign capital, welfare and urban unemployment in the presence of agricultural dualism. Japan and the World Economy, 19(2), 149–165. DOI: 10.1016/j.japwor.2005.08.001
- Dickey D.A., Fuller W.A. (1981). Likelihood ratio statistics for autoregressive time series with a unit root. Econometrica, 49(4). DOI: 10.2307/1912517
- Dornbusch R. (1985). Purchasing Power Parity. Cambridge, MA. DOI: 10.3386/w1591
- Espíndola A.L., Silveira J.J., Penna T.J.P. (2006). A Harris-Todaro agent-based model to rural-urban migration. Brazilian Journal of Physics, 36(3a), 603–609. DOI: 10.1590/S0103-97332006000500002
- Fields G.S. (1975). Rural-urban migration, urban unemployment and underemployment, and job-search activity in LDCs. Journal of Development Economics, 2(2), 165–187. DOI: 10.1016/0304-3878(75)90014-0
- Gimeno-Feliu L.A., Calderón-Larrañaga A., Díaz E. et al. (2019). The definition of immigrant status matters: Impact of nationality, country of origin, and length of stay in host country on mortality estimates. BMC Public Health, 19(1), 247. DOI: 10.1186/s12889-019-6555-1
- Haas H., Czaika M., Flahaux M. et al. (2019). International migration: Trends, determinants, and policy effects. Population and Development Review, 45(4), 885–922. DOI: 10.1111/padr.12291
- Harris J.R., Todaro M.P. (1970). Migration, unemployment and development: A two-sector analysis. American Economic Review, 60.
- Herzog H.W., Schlottmann A.M. (1984). Labor force mobility in the United States: Migration, unemployment, and remigration. International Regional Science Review, 9(1), 43–58. DOI: 10.1177/016001768400900102
- Jean S., Jiménez M. (2011). The unemployment impact of immigration in OECD countries. European Journal of Political Economy, 27(2), 241–256. DOI: 10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2010.11.006
- Kao C. (1999). Spurious regression and residual-based tests for cointegration in panel data. Journal of Econometrics, 90(1), 1–44. DOI: 10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00023-2
- Kemnitz A. (2003). Immigration, unemployment and pensions. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 105(1), 31–48. DOI: 10.1111/1467-9442.00003
- Kingma M. (2007). Nurses on the move: A global overview. Health Services Research, 42(3p2), 1281–1298. DOI: 10.1111/j.1475-6773.2007.00711.x
- Kondoh K., Kurata H. (2021). Agritourism, unemployment, and urban-rural migration. In: Batabyal A.A., Higano Y., Nijkamp P. (Eds.). Rural–Urban Dichotomies and Spatial Development in Asia. New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives. DOI: 10.1007/978-981-16-1232-9_2
- Levin A., Lin C.F., Chu C.S.J. (2002). Unit root tests in panel data: Asymptotic and finite-sample properties. Journal of Econometrics, 108(1). DOI: 10.1016/S0304-4076(01)00098-7
- Nakagome M. (1989). Urban unemployment and the spatial structure of labor markets: An examination of the “Todaro paradox” in a spatial context. Journal of Regional Science, 29(2), 161–170, DOI: 10.1111/j.1467-9787.1989.tb01230.x
- Nordhaus W. (2007). Alternative measures of output in global economic-environmental models: Purchasing power parity or market exchange rates? Energy Economics, 29(3), 349–372, DOI: 10.1016/j.eneco.2006.02.003
- Pedroni P. (1999). Critical values for cointegration tests in heterogeneous panels with multiple regressors. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 61. DOI: 10.1111/1468-0084.61.s1.14
- Pedroni P. (2004). Panel cointegration: Asymptotic and finite sample properties of pooled time series tests with an application to the PPP hypothesis. Econometric Theory, 20(3). DOI: 10.1017/S0266466604203073
- Pesaran M.H. (2004). General Diagnostic Tests for Cross Section Dependence in Panels. Cambridge Working Papers in Economics No. 0435. Center for Economic Studies & Ifo Institute for Economic Research CESifo.
- Pesaran M.H., Ullah A., Yamagata T. (2008). A bias-adjusted LM test of error cross-section independence. Econometrics Journal, 11(1). DOI: 10.1111/j.1368-423X.2007.00227.x
- Pi J., Yin J. (2016). Privatization, unemployment, and welfare in the Harris-Todaro model with a mixed duopoly. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 16(4). DOI: 10.1515/bejeap-2016-0016
- Potts D., Mutambirwa C. (1990). Rural-urban linkages in contemporary Harare: Why migrants need their land. Journal of Southern African Studies, 16(4), 677–698. DOI: 10.1080/03057079008708256
- Puhani P.A. (2001). Labor mobility: An adjustment mechanism in Euroland? Empirical evidence for Western Germany, France and Italy. German Economic Review, 2(2), 127–140, DOI: 10.1111/1468-0475.00031
- Raimondos P. (1993). On the Todaro paradox. Economics Letters, 42(2-3). DOI: 10.1016/0165-1765(93)90071-J
- Ravenstein E.G. (1889). The laws of migration. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 52(2). DOI: 10.2307/2979333
- Samuelson P.A. (1964). Theoretical notes on trade problems. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 46(2), 145. DOI: 10.2307/1928178
- Sancar C., Akbaş Y.E. (2022). The effect of unemployment and urbanization on migration in Turkey: An evaluation in terms of the Harris – Todaro model. Sosyoekonomi. DOI: 10.17233/sosyoekonomi.2022.01.11
- Sevencan A. (2023). Remittances, unemployment, growth and development: A panel cointegration approach. Applied Economics Letters, 30(5), 663–668, DOI: 10.1080/13504851.2021.2009755
- Stark O., Ranjan Gupta M., Levhari D. (1991). Equilibrium urban unemployment in developing countries. Economics Letters, 37(4), 477–482. DOI: 10.1016/0165-1765(91)90090-8
- Takagi Y. (1984). The migration function and the Todaro paradox. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 14(2). DOI: 10.1016/0166-0462(84)90024-3
- Todaro M.P. (1969). A model of labor migration and urban unemployment in less developed countries. The American Economic Review, 59(1).
- Todaro M.P. (1976). Migration and economic development: A review of theory, evidence, methodology and research priorities. Institute for Development Studies, University of Nairobi. Vol. Occasional.
- Wong S.C. (1991). Immigrant autobiography: Some questions of definition and approach. In: Eakin P.J. (Ed.). American Autobiography: Retrospect and Prospect. University of Wisconsin Press.
- Yilmaz E., Sensoy F. (2022). Effects of fossil fuel usage in electricity production on CO2 emissions: A STIRPAT model application on 20 selected countries. International Journal of Energy Economics and Policy, 12(6), 224–229. DOI: 10.32479/ijeep.13707
- Zarembka P. (1970). Labor migration and urban unemployment: Comment. American Economic Review, 60(1).
- Zenou Y. (2005). The Todaro Paradox Revisited. Stockholm.
- Zhang K.H., Song S. (2003). Rural-urban migration and urbanization in China: Evidence from time-series and cross-section analyses. China Economic Review, 14(4), 386–400. DOI: 10.1016/j.chieco.2003.09.018